home *** CD-ROM | disk | FTP | other *** search
- Subject: 87-2048--CONCUR, TEXACO INC. v. HASBROUCK
-
-
-
-
- SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
-
-
- No. 87-2048
-
-
-
- TEXACO INC., PETITIONER v. RICKY HASBROUCK, dba RICK'S TEXACO, et al.
-
- on writ of certiorari to the united states court of appeals for the ninth
- circuit
-
- [June 14, 1990]
-
-
-
- Justice Scalia, with whom Justice Kennedy joins, concurring in the
- judgment.
-
- I agree with the Court that none of the arguments pressed by petitioner
- for removing its conduct from the coverage of the Robinson-Patman Act is
- persuasive. I cannot, however, adopt the Court's reasoning, which seems to
- create an exemption for functional discounts that are "reasonable" even
- though prohibited by the text of the Act.
- The Act provides:
-
- "It shall be unlawful for any person engaged in commerce, in the course
- of such commerce, either directly or indirectly, to discriminate in price
- between different purchasers of commodities of like grade and quality . . .
- where the effect of such discrimination may be substantially to lessen
- competition or tend to create a monopoly in any line of commerce, or to
- injure, destroy, or prevent competition with any person who either grants
- or knowingly receives the benefit of such discrimination, or with customers
- of either of them: Provided, That nothing herein contained shall prevent
- differentials which make only due allowance for differences in the cost of
- manufacture, sale, or delivery resulting from the differing methods or
- quantities in which such commodities are to such purchasers sold or
- delivered." 15 U. S. C. 13(a).
-
- As the Court notes, ante, at 10, sales of like goods in interstate commerce
- violate this provision if three conditions are met: (1) the seller
- discriminates in price between purchasers, (2) the effect of such
- discrimination may be to injure competition between the victim and
- beneficiaries of the discrimination or their customers, and (3) the
- discrimination is not cost- based. Petitioner makes three arguments, one
- related to each of these conditions. First, petitioner argues that a price
- differential between purchasers at different levels of distribution is not
- discrimination in price. As the Court correctly concludes, that cannot be
- so. As long ago as FTC v. Morton Salt Co., 334 U. S. 37 (1948), we held
- that the Act prohibits differentials in the prices offered to wholesalers
- and retailers. True, in Morton Salt the retailers were being favored over
- the wholesalers, the reverse of the situation here. But if that factor
- could make any difference, it would bear not upon whether price
- discrimination occurred, but upon whether it affected competition, the
- point I address next.
- Second, petitioner argues that its practice of giving wholesalers Gull
- and Dompier discounts unavailable to retailer Hasbrouck could not have
- injured Hasbrouck's competition with retailers who purchased from Gull and
- Dompier. Any competitive advantage enjoyed by the competing retailers,
- petitioner asserts, was the product of independent decisions by Gull and
- Dompier to pass on the discounts to those retailers. This also is
- unpersuasive. The Act forbids price discrimination whose effect may be "to
- injure, destroy, or prevent competition with any person who . . . knowingly
- receives the benefit of such discrimination, or with customers of [that
- person]." 15 U. S. C. 13(a) (emphasis added). Obviously, that effect upon
- "competition with customers" occurs whether or not the beneficiary's choice
- to pass on the discount is his own. The existence of an implied "proximate
- cause" requirement that would cut off liability by reason of the voluntary
- act of pass-on is simply implausible. This field is laden with "voluntary
- acts" of third persons that do not relieve the violator of liability,
- beginning with the act of the ultimate purchaser, who in the last analysis
- causes the injury to competition by "voluntarily" choosing to buy from the
- seller who offers the lower price that the price discrimination has made
- possible. The Act focuses not upon free will, but upon predictable
- commercial motivation; and it is just as predictable that a wholesaler will
- ordinarily increase sales (and thus profits) by passing on at least some of
- a price advantage, as it is that a retailer will ordinarily buy at the
- lower price. To say that when the Act refers to injury of competition
- "with customers" of the beneficiary it has in mind only those customers to
- whom the beneficiary is compelled to sell at the lower price is to assume
- that Congress focused upon the damage caused by the rare exception rather
- than the damage caused by the almost universal rule. The Court rightly
- rejects that interpretation. The independence of the pass-on decision is
- beside the point.
- Petitioner's third point relates to the third condition of liability
- (i. e., lack of a cost justification for the discrimination), but does not
- assert that such a justification is present here. Rather, joined by the
- United States as amicus curiae, petitioner argues at length that even if
- petitioner's discounts to Gull and Dompier cannot be shown to be cost-based
- they should be exempted, because the "functional discount" is an efficient
- and legitimate commercial practice that is ordinarily cost-based, though it
- is all but impossible to establish cost justification in a particular case.
- The short answer to this argument is that it should be addressed to
- Congress.
- The Court does not, however, provide that response, but accepts this
- last argument in somewhat modified form. Petitioner has violated the Act,
- it says, only because the discount it gave to Gull and Dompier was not a
- "reasonable reimbursement for the value to [petitioner] of their actual
- marketing functions." Ante, at 16; see also ante, at 25. Relying on a
- mass of extratextual materials, the Court concludes that the Act permits
- such "reasonable" functional discounts even if the supplier cannot satisfy
- the "rigorous requirements of the cost justification defense." Id., at 15.
- I find this conclusion quite puzzling. The language of the Act is
- straightforward: any price discrimination whose effect "may be
- substantially . . . to injure, destroy, or prevent competition" is
- prohibited, unless it is immunized by the "cost justification" defense, i.
- e., unless it "make[s] only due allowance for differences in the cost of
- manufacture, sale, or delivery resulting from the differing methods or
- quantities in which [the] commodities are . . . sold or delivered." 15 U.
- S. C. 13(a). There is no exception for "reasonable" functional discounts
- that do not meet this requirement. Indeed, I am at a loss to understand
- what makes a functional discount "reasonable" unless it meets this
- requirement. It does not have to meet it penny- for-penny, of course: The
- "rigorous requirements of the cost justification defense" to which the
- Court refers, ante, at 15, are not the rigors of mathematical precision,
- but the rigors of proof that the amount of the discount and the amount of
- the cost saving are close enough that the difference cannot produce any
- substantial lessening of competition. See ante, at 15, n. 18. How is one
- to determine that a functional discount is "reasonable" except by proving
- (through the normally, alas, "rigorous" means) that it meets this test?
- Shall we use a nationwide average?
- I suppose a functional discount can be "reasonable" (in the relevant
- sense of being unlikely to subvert the purposes of the Act) if it is not
- commensurate with the supplier's costs saved (as the cost-justification
- defense requires), but is commensurate with the wholesaler's costs incurred
- in performing services for the supplier. Such a discount would not produce
- the proscribed effect upon competition, since if it constitutes only
- reimbursement for the wholesaler one would not expect him to pass it on.
- The relevant measure of the discount in order to determine "reasonableness"
- on that basis, however, is not the measure the Court applies to Texaco
- ("value to [the supplier] of [the distributor's] actual marketing
- functions," ante, at 16), but rather "cost to the distributor of the
- distributor's actual marketing functions", which is of course not
- necessarily the same thing. I am therefore quite unable to understand what
- the Court has in mind by its "reasonable" functional discount that is not
- cost justified.
- To my mind, there is one plausible argument for the proposition that a
- functional basis for differential pricing ipso facto, cost justification or
- not, negates the probability of competitive injury, thus destroying an
- element of the plaintiff's prima facie case, see Falls City Industries,
- Inc. v. Vanco Beverage, Inc., 460 U. S. 428, 434 (1983): In a market that
- is really functionally divided, retailers are in competition with one
- another, not with wholesalers. That competition among retailers cannot be
- injured by the supplier's giving lower prices to wholesalers, because if
- the price differential is passed on, all retailers will simply purchase
- from wholesalers instead of from the supplier. Or, to put it differently,
- when the market is functionally divided all competing retailers have the
- opportunity of obtaining the same price from wholesalers, and the
- supplier's functional price discrimination alone does not cause any injury
- to competition. Therefore (the argument goes), if functional division of
- the market is established, it should be up to the complaining retailer to
- show that some special factor (e. g., an agreement between the supplier and
- the wholesaler that the latter will not sell to the former's
- retailer-customers) prevents this normal market mechanism from operating.
- As the Court notes, ante, at 26, this argument was not raised by the
- parties here or below, and it calls forth a number of issues that would
- benefit from briefing and factual development. I agree that we should not
- decide the merit of this argument in the first instance.
- For the foregoing reasons, I concur in the judgment.
- ------------------------------------------------------------------------------
-